2013년 2월 7일 목요일

[발췌: 일반이론 14장] The Classical Theory of the Rate of Interest

출처: The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money (Keynes, 1936)
자료: MIA(html); eBook; single PDF; Gutenberg(html) (cf. my catalog of his writings)

※ This is a reading note with excerpts taken, and personal annotations and remarks added, in trying to understand the above text, so visit the source links to see the original.

※ 발췌(excerpts):

* * *

Chapter 14_ The Classical Theory of the Rate of Interest

I

What is the classical theory of the rate of interest? It is something upon which we have all been brought up and which we have accepted without much reserve until recently. Yet I find it difficult to state it precisely or to discover an explicit account of it in the leading treatise of the modern classical school.[주1]
[주1] See the Appendix to this Chapter for an abstract of what I have been able to find.
  It is fairly clear, however, that this tradition[classical & modern classical] has regarded the rate of interest as the factor which brings the demand for investment and the willingness to save into equilibrium with one another.
  • Investment represents the demand for investible resources and saving represents the supply, whilst the rate of interest is the ‘price’ of investible resources at which the two are equated. 
  • Just as the price of a commodity is necessarily fixed at that point where the demand for it is equal to the supply, so the rate of interest necessarily comes to rest under the play of market forces at the point where the amount of investment at that rate of interest is equal to the amount of saving at that rate.
  The above is not to be found in Marshall's Principles in so many words. Yet his theory seems to be this, and it is what I myself was brought up on and what I taught for many years to others. Take, for example, the following passage from his Principles: [:]
‘Interest, being the price paid for the use of capital in any market, tends towards an equilibrium level such that the aggregate demand for capital in that market, at that rate of interest, is equal to the aggregate stock forthcoming at that rate.’[주2] 
[주2] CF. Appendix p. 186 below for a further discussion of this passge. 
Or again in Professor Cassel’s Nature and Necessity of Interest it is explained that investment constitutes the ‘demand for waiting’ and saving the ‘supply of waiting’, whilst interest is a ‘price’ which serves, it is implied, to equate the two though here again I have not found actual words to quote. Chapter VI of Professor Carver’s Distribution of Wealth clearly envisages interest as the factor which brings into equilibrium the marginal disutility of waiting with the marginal productivity of capital.[주3]
[주3] Prof. Carver's discussion of Interest is difficult to follow (1) through his inconsistency as to whether he means by "marginal productivity of capital" quantity of marginal product or value of marginal product, and (2) through his making no attempt to define quantity of capital.
Sir Alfred Flux(Economic Principles, p. 95) writes: ‘If there is justice in the contentions of our general discussion, it must be admitted that an automatic adjustment takes place between saving and the opportunities for employing capital profitably... Saving will not have exceeded its possibility of usefulness...so long as the rate of interest is in excess of zero.’ Professor Taussig (Principles, vol. ii. p. 29) draw a supply curve of saving and a demand curve representing ‘the diminishing productiveness of the several instalments of capital’, having previously stated (p. 20) that ‘the rate of interest settles at a point where the marginal productivity of capital suffices to bring out the marginal instalment of saving’,[4]
[주4] In a very recent discussion of these problems ("Capital, Time and Interest Rate", by Prof. F.H. Knight, Economica, August 1932), a discussion which contains many interesting and profound observaations on the nature of capital, and confirms the soundness of the Marshallian tradition as to the usefulness of Böhm-Bawerkian analysis, the theory of interest is given precisely in the traditional, classical mould. Equilibrium in the field of capital production means, according to Prof. Knight, "such a rate of interest that saving flow into the market at precisely the same time-rate or speed as they flow into investment producing the same net rate of return as that which is paid savers for their uses".
Walras, Appendix I (III) of his Eléments d'économie pure, where he deals with ‘l'échange d'épargnes contre capitaux neufs’, argues expressly that, corresponding to each possible rate of interest, there is a sum which individuals will save and also a sum which they will invest in new capital assets, that these two aggregates tend to equality with one another, and that the rate of interest is the variable which brings them to equality; so that the rate of interest is fixed at the point where saving, which represents the supply of new capital, is equal to the demand for it. Thus he is strictly in the classical tradition. 

  Certainly the ordinary man─banker, civil servant or politician─brought up on the traditional theory, and the trained economist also, has carried away with him the idea [:]
  1. that whenever an individual performs an act of saving he has done something which automatically brings down the rate of interest, that this automatically stimulated the output of capital, 
  2. and that the fall in the rate of interest is just so much as is necessary to stimulate the output of capital to an extent which is equal to the increment of saving ; 
  3. and, further, that this is a self-regulatory process of adjustment which takes place without the necessity for any special intervention or grandmotherly care on the part of the monetary authority. 
  4. Similarly─and this is an even more general belief, even to-day─each additional act of investment will necessarily raise the rate of interest, if it is not offset by a change in the readiness to save.
  Now the analysis of the previous chapters[11, 12, 13] will have made it plain this account of the matter must be erroneous. In tracing to its source the reason for the difference of opinion, let us, however, begin with the matters which are agreed. [※ 위 1~4와 같은 설명이 잘못됐다는 것은 앞의 장들에서 분명해졌을 것이다. 하지만 어째서 고전파의 설명과 나의 설명이 갈라지는 것인지 그 근원을 파헤치기 위해 서로 일치하는 논점부터 거론해보자.]

[새 문단]
  • Unlike the neo-classical school, who believe that saving and investment can be actually unequal, the classical school proper has accepted (1) the view that they are equal. Marshall, for example, surely believed, although he did not expressly say so, that aggregate saving and aggregate investment are necessarily equal. Indeed, most members of the classical school carried this belief much too far; since they held that every act of increased saving by an individual necessarily brings into existence a corresponding act of increased investment. 
  • (2) Nor is there any material difference, relevant in this context, between my schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital or investment demand-schedule and the demand curve for capital contemplated by some of the classical writers who have been quoted above. 
  • When we come to the propensity to consume and its corollary the propensity to save, we are nearer to a difference of opinion, owing to the emphasis which they have placed on the influence of the rate of interest on the propensity to save.[※ 소비성향(및 그로부터 파생되는 저축성향) 문제를 볼 때는 금리가 저축성향을 좌우하는 영향력을 강조한다는 점에서 의견이 갈리는 지점에 근접하게 되다. (그러나)] But (3) they would, presumably, not wish to deny that the level of income also has an important influence on the amount saved; whilst I, for my part, would not deny that the rate of interest may perhaps have an influence (though perhaps not of the kind which they suppose) on the amount saved out of a given income
All these points of agreement[위 (1), (2), (3)can be summed up in a proposition(a) which the classical school would accept and I should not dispute; namely,
  • (a) that, if the level of income is assumed to be given, we can infer that the current rate of interest must lie at the point where the demand curve for capital corresponding to different rates of interest cuts the curve of the amounts saved out of the given income corresponding to different rates of interest. [※ 대략, ∀ Y, ∃ r such that D(r)=S(r, Y) ]
But this is the point at which definite error creeps into the classical theory.
[1] If the classical school merely inferred from the above proposition(a) [:]
  • (b) that, given the demand curve for capital and the influence of changes in the rate of interest on the readiness to save out of given income, the level of income and the rate of interest must be uniquely correlated, [※  대략, ∀ D(r) & ∂S(r, Y)/∂r,  ∃ f such that r=f(Y) ]
there would be nothing to quarrel with. 
[2] Moreover, this proposition[b? 혹은 b를 포함한 a] would lead naturally to another proposition which embodies an important truth; namely,[:]
  • (c) that, if the rate of interest is given as well as the demand curve for capital and the influence of the rate of interest on the readiness to save out of given levels of income, the level of income must be the factor which brings the amount saved to equality with the amount invested. [※ 대략,  ∀ r & D(r) & ∂S(r, Y)/∂r, ∃ Y such that S(r, Y)=D(r) ]
[3] But, in fact, the classical theory not merely neglects the influence of changes in the level of income, but involves formal error.
  For classical theory, as can be seem from the above quotations, assumes that it can then proceed to consider the effect on the rate of interest of (e.g.) a shift in the demand curve for capital, without abating or modifying its assumption as to the amount of the given income out of which the savings are to be made.
※ 쉽게 말해, 고전파 이론은 저축을 결정하는 데 참여하는 소득 수준을 고려하지 않고then[명제 (a), (b), (c)로부터]ㅡ(가령) 자본 수요곡선의 이동이 금리에 미치는 영향를 거론할 수 있다고 본다.
  • The independent variables of the classical theory of the rate of interest are the demand curve for capital and the influence of the rate of interest on the amount saved out of a given income ; [※ 고전파 이론에서 금리를 결정하는 독립변수 두 개는 자본 수요곡선과 주어진 소득 가운데 금리에 따라 달라지는 저축액이다. ]
  • and when (e.g.) the demand curve for capital shifts, the new rate of interest, according to this theory, is given by the point of intersection between the new demand curve for capital and the curve relating the rate of interest to the amount which will be saved out the given income. 
The classical theory of the rate of interest seems to suppose that,[:]
if the demand curve for capital shifts or if the curve relating the rate of interest to the amounts saved out of a given income shifts or if both these curves shit, the new rate of interest will be given by the point of intersection of the new positions of the two curves.
But this is a nonsense theory. For[:]
the assumption that income is constant is inconsistent with the assumption that these two curves can shift independently of one another. If either of them shift, then, in general, income will change; with the result that the whole schematism based on the assumption of a given income breaks down.
  1. The position could only be saved by some complicated assumption providing for an automatic change in the wage-unit of an amount just sufficient in its effect on liquidity-preference to establish a rate of interest which would just offset the supposed shift, so as to leave output at the same level as before. In fact, there is no hint to be found in the above writers as to the necessity for any such assumption; 
  2. at the best it would be plausible only in relation to long-period equilibrium and could not form the basis of a short-period theory.; 
  3. and there is no ground for supposing it to hold in the long-period. 
In truth, the classical theory has not been alive to the relevance of (1) changes in the level of income or (2) the possibility of the level of income being actually a function of the rate of investment.

  The above can be illustrated by a diagram[5] as follows: In this diagram the amount of investment (or saving) I is measured vertically, and the rate of interest r horizontally. X1X1' is the first position of the investment demand-schedule, and X2X2' is a second position of this curve. The curve Y1 relates the amount saved out of an income Y1 to various levels of the rate of interest, the curves Y2, Y3, etc., being the corresponding curves for levels of income Y2, Y3, etc. (1) Let us suppose that the curve Y1 is the Y-curve consistent with an investment demand-schedule X1X1' and the rate of interest r1. (2) Now if the investment demand-schedule shifts from X1X1' to X2X2', income will, in general, shifts also.
  1. But the above diagram does not contain enough data to tell us what its new value will be; and, therefore, not knowing which is the appropriate Y-curve, we do not know at what point the new investment demand-schedule will cut it. 
  2. If, however, we introduce the state of liquidity-preference and the quantity of money and these between them tell us that the rate of interest is r2, then the whole position becomes determinate. For the Y-curve which intersects X2X2' at the point vertically above r2, namely, the curve Y2, will be the appropriate curve. 
  3. Thus X-curve and the Y-curve tell us nothing about the rate of interest. They only tell us what income will be, if from some other source we can say what the rate of interest is. 
  4. If nothing has happened to the state of liquidity-preference and the quantity of money, so that the rate of interest is unchanged, then the curve Y2' which intersects the new investment demand-schedule vertically below the point where the curve Y1 intersected the old investment demand-schedule will be the appropriate Y-curve, and Y2' will be the new level of income.
[주5] This diagram was suggested to me by Mr. R.F. Harrod. Cf. also a partly similar schematism by Mr. D.H. Robertson, Economic Journal, December 1934, p. 652.
  Thus the functions used by the classical theory, namely, the response of investment and the response of the amount saved out of a given income to change in the rate of interest, do not furnish material for a theory of the rate of interest; but they could be used to tell us what the level of income will be, given (from some other source) the rate of interest; and, alternatively, what the rate of interest will have to be, if the level of income is to be maintained at a give figure (e.g. the level corresponding to full employment).

  The mistake originates from regarding interest as the reward for waiting as such, instead of as the reward for not-hoarding; just as the rates of return on loans or investments involving different degrees of risk, are quite properly regarded as the reward, not of waiting as such, but of running the risk. There is, in truth, no sharp line between these[rates of return on loans/investments] and the so-called ‘pure’ rate of interest, all of them being the reward for running the risk of uncertainty of one kind or another. Only in the event of money being used solely for transactions and never as a store of value, would a different theory become appropriate.[6]
[주6] Cf. Chapter 17 below
  There are, however, two familiar points which might, perhaps, have warned the classical school that something was wrong. In the first place it has been agreed, at any rate since the publication of Professor Cassel's Nature and Necessity of Interest, (a1) that it is not certain that the sum saved out of a given income necessarily increases when the rate of interest is increased; (a2) whereas no one doubts that the investment demand-schedule falls with a rising rate of interest. But if the Y-curves and X-curves both fall as the rate of interest rises[※ (a1)으로부터 만일 X 곡선들뿐 아니라 Y 곡선들도 우하향한다고 가정하면], there is no guarantee that a given Y-curve will intersect a given X-curve anywhere at all. This suggests that it cannot be the Y-curve and X-curve alone which determine the rate of interest.

  In the second place, it has been usual to suppose that an increase in the quantity of money has a tendency to reduce the rate of interest, at any rate in the first instance and in the short period. Yet no reason has been given why a change in the quantity of money should affect either the investment demand-schedule or the readiness to save out of a given income.  Thus the classical school have had quite a different theory of the rate of interest in volume Ⅰ dealing with the theory of value from what they have had in volume Ⅱ dealing with the theory of money. They have seemed undisturbed by the conflict and have made no attempt, so far as I know, to build a bridge between the two theories.
 고전파는 통화량 증가가 금리를 떨어뜨린다고 보면서, 통화량 증가가 왜 투자수요 계획과 저축 공급에 영향을 미치는지 거론하지 않았다. 그러니 고전학파는 화폐이론에서 다루는 금리이론과 가치이론에서 다루는 금리이론이 아주 달랐다는 이야기다. 고전파는 서로 다른 두 이론의 상충을 괘념치 않았고 그 두 이론을 연결시키려고 하지 않았다.
The classical school proper that is to say; since it is the attempt to build a bridge on the part of the neo-classical school which has led to the worst muddles of all.
본래의 고전학파가 그랬다는 이야기다. 왜냐하면 신고전학파는 이 두 가지 이론을 연결시키려고 했기 때문이다. 그런데 신고전파의 이 시도로 말미암아 금리이론은 최악의 엉망진창이 되고 말았다. [왜 그런가?] 
For[:]
  1. the latter[the neo-classical school] have inferred that there must be two sources of supply to meet the investment demand-schedule; namely, (1) savings proper, which are the savings dealt with by the classical school, plus the sum made available by (2) any increase in the quantity of money (this being balanced by some species of levy on the public, called ‘forced saving’ or the like). 
  2. This leads on to (a) the idea that there is a ‘natural’ or ‘neutral’[7] or ‘equilibrium’ rate of interest, namely, that rate of interest which equates investment to classical savings proper without any addition from ‘forced savings’; and finally [leads on] to (b) what, assuming they are on the right track at the start, is the most obvious solution of all, namely, that, if the quantity of money could only be kept constant in all circumstances, none of these complications would arise, since the evils supposed to result from the supposed excess of investment over savings proper would cease to be possible. But at this point we are in deep water. The wild duck has dived down to the bottom─as deep as she can get─and bitten fast hold of the weed and tangle and all the rubbish that is down there, and it would need an extraordinary clever dog to dive after and fish her up again.
[주7] The “neutral” rate of interest of contemporary economists is different both from the “natural” rate of Böhm-Bawerk and from the “natural” rate of Wicksell.
  Thus the traditional analysis is faulty because it has failed to isolate correctly the independent variables of the system.
  1. Saving and investment are the determinates of the system, not the determinants. 
  2. They are the twin results of the system's determinants, namely (1) the propensity to consume, (2) the schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital and (3) the rate of interest. 
  3. These determinants[(1), (2), (3)] are, indeed, themselves complex and each is capable of being affected by prospective changes in the others. But they remain independent in the sense that their values cannot be inferred from one another
  4. The traditional analysis has been aware that saving depends on income but it has overlooked the fact that income depends on investment, in such fashion that, when investment changes, income must necessarily change in just that degree which is necessary to make the change in saving equal to the change in investment.
  Nor are those theories more successful which attempt to make the rate of interest depend on ‘the marginal efficiency of capital’. It is true that in equilibrium the rate of interest will be equal to the marginal efficiency of capital, since it will be profitable to increase (or decrease) the current scale of investment until the point of equality has been reached. But [:]
  • to make this into a theory of the rate of interest or to derive the rate of interest from it involves a circular argument, as Marshall discovered after he had got half-way into giving an account of the rate of interest along these line.[주8: see app.] For the ‘marginal efficiency of capital’ partly depends on the scale of current investment, and we must already know the rate of interest before we can calculate what this scale will be. [※ 금리←자본의 한계효율←당기 투자 규모←(다시)금리의 순환논리 ]
  • The significant conclusion is [:]
  1. that the output of new investment will be pushed to the point at which the marginal efficiency of capital becomes equal to the rate of interest; 
  2. and what the schedule of the marginal efficiency of capital tells us, is, not what the rate of interest is, but the point to which the output of new investment will be pushed, given the rate of interest.
  The reader will readily appreciate that the problem here under discussion is a matter of the most fundamental theoretical significance and of overwhelming practical importance. For the economic principle, on which the practical advice of economists has been almost invariably based, has assumed, in effect, that, cet. par., a decrease in spending[소비의 감소, 즉 주어진 소득에서 저축 증가] will tend to lower the rate of interest and an increase in investment to raise it. But if what these two quantities[소비(저축), 투자] determine is, not the rate of interest, but the aggregate volume of employment, then our outlook on the mechanism of the economic system will be profoundly changed. A decreased readiness to spend will be looked on in a quite different light if, instead of being regarded as a factor which will, cet. par., increase investment, it is seen as a factor which will, cet. par., diminish employment.


주석 ..

댓글 없음:

댓글 쓰기